Pages

Welcome, 77 artists, 40 different points of Attica welcomes you by singing Erotokritos an epic romance written at 1713 by Vitsentzos Kornaros

Tuesday, April 9, 2013

Immigrants target Greece's sea border


Kathimerini

Immigrants target Greece's sea border
Kathimerini
Installation of a barbed-wire fence and tightened security measures on Greece's land border with Turkey have led to an increase in the number of clandestine immigrants seeking to sneak into Europe through the eastern Aegean Sea during the first quarter ...


READ THE ORIGINAL POST AT www.ekathimerini.com

Fresh anxiety over Greece and Portugal


This is Money

Fresh anxiety over Greece and Portugal
This is Money
Prices in Greece fell last month for the first time in 45 years as the country's savage recession sparked deflation. Figures released today showed prices dropped 0.2 per cent year-on-year in March, as Greece suffered its sixth year of recession under ...
'TOP SECRET' report may reveal Germany owes Greece billions of euroseuronews
Greece: £140bn German War Reparations Debts Dossier LeakedIBTimes.co.uk
Germany owes Greece billions in WWII reparations: Secret reportPress TV
Huffington Post UK -Kathimerini
all 15 news articles »

READ THE ORIGINAL POST AT www.thisismoney.co.uk

Greece sells €1.3bn 6-month T-Bills


Greece sells €1.3bn 6-month T-Bills
EnetEnglish
Some €1.3bn of six-month T-bills were have been sold to roll over a previous issue that comes due on April 12, the Public Debt Management Agency said on Tuesday. The T-bills were priced to yield 4.25%, unchanged from a previous March 5 auction.
Greece sells 1.3 bln eur 6-month T-Bills, yield steadyReuters
Greece sells 1.3-bln-euro treasury bills in new auctionGlobal Times
Greek borrowing rates unchanged in latest auctionRTE.ie

all 4 news articles »

READ THE ORIGINAL POST AT www.enetenglish.gr

Big Catch For Greek Fish Farms


All about feed

Big Catch For Greek Fish Farms
Greek Reporter
The new company expects to sell more than 40,000 ton of fish annually, about 35% of Greece's total production of sea bass and sea bream, and the total annual volume of exports of fresh Greek sea bream and sea bass to over 20 countries will exceed 35 ...
Merger to produce world largest bass and bream producerWorld Fishing
Big fish farming merger agreedEnetEnglish

all 5 news articles »

READ THE ORIGINAL POST AT greece.greekreporter.com

Big Gains in Greece ETF, Can It Last?


Big Gains in Greece ETF, Can It Last?
Zacks.com
Although other European markets have taken over the limelight, the situation in Greece should still be of concern to investors. The country remains highly indebted, has a troublingunemployment rate, and has little prospects for growth in the near future.


READ THE ORIGINAL POST AT www.zacks.com

Deflation takes hold in Greece


Telegraph.co.uk

Deflation takes hold in Greece
Financial Times
Greece has seen persistent inflation in spite of a prolonged recession now in its sixth year, reflecting increases in indirect taxation and slow progress with market reforms as the government struggles to achieve targets set by international lenders.
Greece enters deflation for first time in 45 yearsTelegraph.co.uk
Greece registers first annual price decline since 1968Gulf Today
First Negative Inflation In Greece In 45 yearsGreek Reporter
Reuters
all 9 news articles »

READ THE ORIGINAL POST AT www.ft.com

Clock ticking on Cyprus deal

Bailout tension rises as panicked politicians warn island could be just weeks away from running out of money

The clock is ticking on Cyprus, where the government calculates it is only a matter of weeks before the Mediterranean island runs out of money.

Highlighting the tiny nation's overnight transition from prosperity to penury, panic-stricken officials have said it is imperative a controversial €10bn bailout is approved by EU parliaments and sealed with international lenders by 24 April.

If an agreement fails to be reached by then – and bailout funds are not there to replenish dried up coffers – President Nicos Anastasiades' administration will face the daunting prospect of being unable to pay state salaries and pensions.

MPs were brought face-to-face with the stark reality of the country going bust when the government's accountant general, Rea Georgiou, admitted an €80m shortfall in state funding – far higher than previously estimated by the previous communist-led government. "The cash deficit for April is €160m. The €85m in reserve is not enough and we need a similar amount to avoid a default," she told parliament.

In echoes of the crisis that has long engulfed Greece, Nicosia's new finance minister, Harris Georgiadis, insisted it was vital that internationally mandated structural reforms were passed. Barely a week into the job, he said the 56-member Cypriot House would have to ratify the measures, including tax increases and spending cuts, in the coming days so a first tranche of aid could be disbursed.

"We are currently at a borderline point," the politician told reporters Monday as a parliamentary economics committee began an inquiry into the handling of the crisis and why Cyprus had been brought to the brink of bankruptcy.

Although the island – in a first for any eurozone member – agreed, under unprecedented German pressure, to "bail in" bank depositors as part of the rescue, in addition to winding down its second-largest lender and radically restructuring its banking sector, the IMF has not fully consented to participating in the programme.

Final approval from the Washington-based body, which in principle will contribute €1bn of the total amount, is expected in May.

The euro group of single currency finance ministers are due to begin the ratification process when they meet in Dublin on Friday.

Depositors were told this week that they must also wait an agonising two to three months before learning the full extent of the enforced losses they have been called to suffer as a result of the bailout.

Well-briefed sources have been widely quoted as saying the haircut on uninsured deposits of more than 100,000 euro at the Bank of Cyprus, the island's largest commercial lender, is unlikely to be less than 50%.

"The extra time is needed to assess assets belonging to the Bank of Cyprus and, as such, its recapitalisation needs," said former central bank governor, Afxentis Afxentiou. "But please quote me as also saying that the way Cyprus has been treated is totally unfair. There has been absolutely no EU solidarity in our case," he told the Guardian. "A lot of ordinary people with life savings stand to be effected."

Greek Cypriot banks saw €4.5bn in deposits – the equivalent of 25% of GDP – wiped out virtually overnight when Greece's monumental debt load, in another one-off move, was restructured last year.

Rumours of a haircut on bank accounts held in local co-operatives sparked a mini-run on the financial institutions last week.

With the sheer scale of the losses sinking in – and anger at the perceived inequity of the deal also mounting – there is growing debate as to whether the EU's most easterly member would be better off leaving the bloc.

Local fury intensified on Tuesday when it was revealed in parliament that tens of millions of euros in cash had been withdrawn from Cypriot banks in the weeks running up to the bailout.

Capital controls, implemented to stop money flooding out of the island, has helped energise calls for a return to the Cyprus pound.

Indicative of the climate, Stavros Malas, who ran for president with the support of the Akel anti-austerity communist party in elections six weeks ago, refused to rule out Nicosia exiting the euro.

"It's one thing to be pro-European, another a masochist," he told Athens' leftwing daily Efimerida twn Syntakton. "Given that the economic crisis in Cyprus will be prolonged, I am absolutely sure that voices will multiply for [the island] to exit the eurozone. And perhaps we would be better off studying this scenario, at least from a macroeconomic point of view."


guardian.co.uk © 2013 Guardian News and Media Limited or its affiliated companies. All rights reserved. | Use of this content is subject to our Terms & Conditions | More Feeds


READ THE ORIGINAL POST AT www.guardian.co.uk

Greece man charged with assaulting woman, baby


News 10NBC

Greece man charged with assaulting woman, baby
Rochester Democrat and Chronicle
According to Greece Police, Akil Mabry, 20, has been charged with two counts of second-degree assault, a felony and misdemeanor charges of third-degree assault and endangering the welfare of a child for incidents that allegedly took place on Milford ...
Police: Greece man assaulted four-month-old babyNews 10NBC
Greece man charged with assaulting woman, childGreece Post
Man Charged After Assaulting Woman and Four Month OldRochester YNN

all 4 news articles »

READ THE ORIGINAL POST AT www.democratandchronicle.com

George Soros: how to save the EU from the euro crisis

There is now a real danger that the euro crisis may end up destroying the European Union

My objective in coming here today is to discuss the euro crisis. In light of the latest developments, I think you will all agree that the crisis is far from resolved. It has already caused tremendous damage both financially and politically and taken an extensive human toll as well. The crisis has also transformed the European Union into something radically different from what was originally intended. The EU was meant to be a voluntary association of equal states but the crisis has turned it into a hierarchy with Germany and other creditors in charge and the heavily indebted countries relegated to second-class status. While in theory Germany cannot dictate policy, in practice no policy can be proposed without obtaining Germany's permission first. To make matters worse, the austerity policy promoted by Germany has the effect of prolonging the crisis and perpetuating the subordination of debtor countries.

 

This has created political tensions as demonstrated by the political stalemate in Italy. Italy now has a majority opposed to the euro and the trend is likely to grow. There is now a real danger that the euro crisis may end up destroying the European Union. A disorderly disintegration would leave Europe worse off than it was when the bold experiment of creating a European Union was begun. That would be a tragedy of historic proportions. But It can be prevented only by Germany with Germany's leadership. Germany did not seek to occupy a dominant position and has been reluctant to accept the responsibilities and liabilities that go with it. That is one of the reasons why the current situation has arisen. But willingly or not, Germany is in the driver's seat and that is what brings me here.

 

How did Europe get into such a mess? And how can it escape from it? These are the two questions I want to address. The answer to the first question is extremely complicated because the euro crisis is extremely complex. It has both a political and a financial dimension. And the financial dimension can be divided into at least three components: a sovereign debt crisis and a banking crisis, as well as divergences in competitiveness.  The various aspects are interconnected, making the problems so complicated that they boggle the mind. In my view the euro crisis cannot be properly understood without realising the crucial role that mistakes and misconceptions have played in creating it. The crisis is almost entirely self-inflicted. It has the quality of a nightmare.

 

By contrast, the answer to the second question is extremely simple. Once we have gained a proper understanding of the problems the solution practically suggests itself.

 

I shall argue that Germany bears a large share of the responsibility for the policy errors that have created the crisis. But I want to make it clear in advance that I am not blaming Germany.  Whoever was in charge would have made similar mistakes. I can say from personal experience that nobody could have understood the situation in all its complexity at the time it unfolded.

 

I realize that I risk antagonising you by putting the responsibility on Germany. But only Germany can put things right. I am a great believer in the European Union and I don't want to see it destroyed. I also care about the immense and unnecessary human suffering that the euro crisis is causing and I want to do whatever I can to mitigate it. My interpretation of the euro crisis is very different from the views prevailing in Germany. I hope that by offering you a different perspective I may get you to reconsider your position before more damage is done. That is my goal in coming here.

 

The European Union was a bold project that fired many people's imagination, including mine. I regarded the European Union as the embodiment of an open society – a voluntary association of equal states who surrendered part of their sovereignty for the common good. The European Union had five large member states and a number of small ones and they all subscribed to the principles of democracy, individual freedom, human rights and the rule of law. No nation or nationality occupied a dominant position.

 

The process of integration was spearheaded by a small group of far sighted statesmen who recognised that perfection was unattainable and practiced what Karl Popper called piecemeal social engineering. They set themselves limited objectives and firm timelines and then mobilised the political will for a small step forward, knowing full well that when they achieved it, its inadequacy would become apparent and require a further step. The process fed on its own success, very much like a boom-bust sequence in financial markets. That is how the Coal and Steel Community was gradually transformed into the European Union, step by step.

 

France and Germany used to be in the forefront of the effort. When the Soviet empire started to disintegrate, Germany's leaders realized that reunification was possible only in the context of a more united Europe and they were prepared to make considerable sacrifices to achieve it. When it came to bargaining, they were willing to contribute a little more and take a little less than the others, thereby facilitating agreement. At that time, German statesmen used to say that Germany has no independent foreign policy, only a European one. This led to a dramatic acceleration of the process. It culminated with the reunification of Germany in 1990 and the signing of the Maastricht treaty in 1992. That was followed by a period of consolidation which lasted until the financial crisis of 2007-8.

 

Unfortunately, the Maastricht treaty was fundamentally flawed. The architects of the euro recognised that it was an incomplete construct: a currency union without a political union. The architects had reason to believe, however, that when the need arose, the political will to take the next step forward could be mobilized. After all, that was how the process of integration had worked until then.

 

But the euro had many other defects, of which neither the architects nor the member states were fully aware. For instance, the Maastricht Treaty took it for granted that only the public sector could produce chronic deficits because the private sector would always correct its own excesses. The financial crisis of 2007-8 proved that wrong. The financial crisis also revealed a near fatal defect in the construction of the euro: by creating an independent central bank, member countries became indebted in a currency they did not control. This exposed them to the risk of default.

 

Developed countries have no reason to default; they can always print money. Their currency may depreciate in value, but the risk of default is practically nonexistent. By contrast, less developed countries that have to borrow in a foreign currency run the risk of default. To make matters worse, financial markets can actually drive such countries into default through bear raids. The risk of default relegated some member countries to the status of a third world country that became over-indebted in a foreign currency.

 

Prior to the financial crisis of 2007-8 both the authorities and the financial markets ignored this feature of the euro. When the euro was introduced, government bonds were treated as riskless. The regulators allowed commercial banks to buy unlimited amounts of government bonds without setting aside any equity capital, and the European Central Bank accepted all government bonds at its discount window on equal terms. This created a perverse incentive for commercial banks to accumulate the bonds of the weaker member countries, which paid higher rates, in order to earn a few extra basis points. As a result interest rate differentials between the various government bonds practically disappeared.

 

The convergence of interest rates caused a divergence in economic performance. The so-called periphery countries, Spain and Ireland foremost among them, enjoyed real estate, investment and consumption booms that made them less competitive, while Germany, weighed down by the cost of reunification, engaged in far-reaching labour market and other structural reforms that made it more competitive.

 

In the week following the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers, the global financial markets literally ceased to function and had to be put on artificial life support. This required substituting sovereign credit (in the form of central bank guarantees and budget deficits) for the credit of the financial institutions whose standing was impaired. The emphasis placed on sovereign credit revealed the hitherto ignored feature of the euro, namely that by creating an independent central bank the euro member countries signed away part of their sovereign status.

 

That would have been the moment to take the next step toward fiscal as well as monetary union but the political will was lacking. Germany, weighed down by the costs of reunification, was no longer in the forefront of integration. Chancellor Merkel read public opinion correctly when she declared that each country should look after its own financial institutions instead of the European Union doing it collectively. That was a step backwards. In retrospect it was the beginning of a process of disintegration.

 

It took financial markets more than a year to realize the implications of chancellor Merkel's declaration, demonstrating that they too operate with far-from-perfect knowledge. Only at the end of 2009, when the extent of the Greek deficit was revealed, did the financial markets realize that a member country could actually default. But then the markets raised the risk premiums on the weaker countries with a vengeance. This rendered commercial banks whose balance sheets were loaded with those bonds potentially insolvent and that created both a sovereign debt and a banking crisis. The two are linked together like Siamese twins.

 

There is a close parallel between the euro crisis and the international banking crisis of 1982. Then the IMF and the international banking authorities saved the international banking system by lending just enough money to the heavily indebted countries to enable them to avoid default but at the cost of pushing them into a lasting depression. Latin America suffered a lost decade.

 

Today Germany is playing the same role as the IMF did then. The setting differs, but the effect is the same.  The creditors are in effect shifting the whole burden of adjustment on to the debtor countries and avoiding their own responsibility for the imbalances. Interestingly, the terms "center" and "periphery" have crept into usage almost unnoticed, although in political terms it is obviously inappropriate to describe Italy and Spain as the periphery of the European Union. In effect, however, the euro had turned their government bonds into bonds of third world countries that carry the risk of default. This fact was ignored by the authorities and it is still not properly recognised. In retrospect, that was the root cause of the euro crisis.

 

Just as in the 1980s, all the blame and burden fell on the "periphery" and the responsibility of the "center" has never been properly acknowledged. The periphery countries are criticized for their lack of fiscal discipline and work ethic, but there is more to it than that. Admittedly the periphery countries need to make structural reforms, just as Germany did after reunification. But to deny that the euro itself has some structural problems that need to be corrected is to ignore the root cause of the euro crisis. Yet that is what is happening.

 

In this context the German word "Schuld" plays a key role. As you know it means both debt and responsibility or guilt. This has made it natural or "selbstverständlich" for German public opinion to blame the heavily indebted countries for their misfortune. The fact that Greece blatantly broke the rules has helped to support this attitude. But other countries like Spain and Ireland had played by the rules; indeed Spain used to be held up as a paragon of virtue. Clearly, the faults are systemic and the misfortunes of the heavily indebted countries are largely caused by the rules that govern the euro. That is the point I would like to drive home today.

 

In my opinion, the "Schuld" or responsibility of the "center" is even greater today than it was in the banking crisis of 1982. It may have been politically acceptable in 1982 to inflict austerity on the less developed countries in order to save the international financial system; but doing the same within the eurozone today cannot be reconciled with the European Union as a voluntary association of equal states. There is an unresolved conflict between what is dictated by financial necessity and what is politically acceptable. That is the point the recent Italian elections should have driven home. 

 

The burden of responsibility falls mainly on Germany. The Bundesbank helped design the blueprint for the euro whose defects put Germany into the driver's seat. This has created two problems. One is political, the other financial. It is the combination of the two that has rendered the situation so intractable.

 

The political problem is that Germany did not seek the dominant position into which it has been thrust and it is unwilling to accept the obligations and liabilities that go with it. Germany understandably doesn't want to be the "deep pocket" for the euro. So it extends just enough support to avoid default but nothing more, and as soon as the pressure from the financial markets abates it seeks to tighten the conditions on which the support is given.

 

The financial problem is that Germany is imposing the wrong policies on the eurozone. Austerity doesn't work. You cannot shrink the debt burden by shrinking the budget deficit. The debt burden is a ratio between the accumulated debt and the GDP, both expressed in nominal terms.  And in conditions of inadequate demand, budget cuts cause a more than proportionate reduction in the GDP — in technical terms the so-called fiscal multiplier is greater than one.

 

The German public finds this difficult to understand. The fiscal and structural reforms undertaken by the Schroeder government worked in 2006; why shouldn't they work for the eurozone a few years later? The answer is that austerity works by increasing exports and reducing imports. When everybody is doing the same thing it simply doesn't work.

 

The euro crisis reached a climax last summer. Financial markets started to anticipate a possible breakup and risk premiums reached unsustainable levels. As a last resort, chancellor Merkel endorsed the president of the European Central Bank, Mario Draghi, against her own nominee, Jens Weidmann. Draghi rose to the occasion. He declared that the ECB would do "whatever it takes" to protect the euro and backed it up by introducing the so-called Open Market Transactions. Financial markets were reassured and embarked on a powerful relief rally. But the jubilation was premature. As soon as the pressure from the financial markets abated, Germany started to whittle down the promises it had made at the height of the crisis.

 

In the bailout of Cyprus, Germany went too far. In order to minimize the cost of the bailout it insisted on bailing in bank depositors. This was premature.  If it had happened after a banking union had been established and the banks recapitalised, it might have been a healthy development. But it came at a time when the banking system was retreating into national silos and remained very vulnerable. What happened in Cyprus undermined the business model of European banks, which relies heavily on deposits. Until now the authorities went out of their way to protect depositors. Cyprus has changed that. Attention is focused on the impact of the rescue on Cyprus but the impact on the banking system is far more important. Banks will have to pay risk premiums that will fall more heavily on weaker banks and the banks of weaker countries. The insidious link between the cost of sovereign debt and bank debt will be reinforced. The playing field will become even more uneven than before.

 

Chancellor Merkel would have liked to put the euro crisis on ice at least until after the elections, but it is back in force. The German public may be unaware of this because Cyprus was a tremendous political victory for Chancellor Merkel. No country will dare to challenge her will. Moreover, Germany itself remains relatively unaffected by the deepening depression that is enveloping the eurozone. I expect, however, that by the time of the elections Germany will also be in recession. That is because the monetary policy pursued by the eurozone is out of sync with the other major currencies. The others are engaged in quantitative easing. The Bank of Japan was the last holdout but it changed sides recently. A weaker yen coupled with the weakness in Europe is bound to affect Germany's exports.

 

 

If my analysis is correct, a simple solution suggests itself. It can be summed up in one word: eurobonds.

 

Eurobonds are the joint and several obligations of all member states. If countries that abide by the fiscal compact were allowed to convert their entire existing stock of government debt into eurobonds, the positive impact would be little short of the miraculous. The danger of default would disappear and so would the risk premiums. The balance sheets of the banks would receive an immediate boost and so would the budgets of the heavily indebted countries because it would cost them less to service their existing stock of government debt. Italy, for instance, would save up to 4% of its GDP. Its budget would move into surplus and instead of austerity, the government could apply fiscal stimulus. The economy would grow and the debt ratio would fall. Most of the seemingly intractable problems would vanish into thin air. Only the divergences in competitiveness would remain unresolved. Individual countries would still need structural reforms, but the main structural defect of the euro would be cured. It would be truly like waking from a nightmare.

 

To avoid any misunderstanding, I am proposing the conversion of the existing stock of government bonds into eurobonds, not the redemption scheme put forward by chancellor's council of economic advisors.

 

This is how my proposal would work. The eurozone would establish a fiscal authority that would be in charge of issuing eurobonds. Its board would be composed of the finance ministers with an independent chairman elected by the board. Voting would be weighted by the GDP of each country. Countries that are in violation of the fiscal compact would not be allowed to vote. Countries that are in compliance would be allowed, but not required to convert their national debt into eurobonds.

 

The fiscal compact provides adequate safeguards against the risk involved in a joint and several obligation. In accordance with the fiscal compact they member countries would be allowed to issue new bonds and bills only to replace maturing ones, but nothing more; after five years the debt outstanding would gradually be reduced to 60% of GDP. If a country fell out of compliance, the fiscal authority it would be penalised it by restricting the amount of eurobonds it would be allowed to issue; it would have to borrow the balance in its own name and pay heavy risk premiums.

 

Germany is opposed to eurobonds on the grounds that once they are introduced there can be no assurance that the so-called periphery countries would not break the rules once again. I believe these fears are misplaced. Losing the privilege of issuing eurobonds and having to pay stiff risk premiums would be a powerful inducement to stay in compliance. Indeed the penalty would be so painful that the rules would have to call for small doses in order not to aggravate the offending country's financial position too abruptly. At the same time a the fiscal authority in charge would exercise stricter controls and disobedience would be punished by further reductions in the amount of eurobonds allowed to be issued. No government could resist such pressure.

 

There are also widespread fears that eurobonds would ruin Germany's credit rating. eurobonds are often compared with the Marshall Plan. The argument goes that the Marshall Plan cost only a few percentage points of America's GDP while eurobonds would cost a multiple of Germany's GDP. That argument is comparing apples with oranges. The Marshall Plan was an actual expenditure while eurobonds would involve a guarantee that will never be called upon. The cost to Germany of agreeing to eurobonds has been greatly exaggerated.

 

Guarantees have a peculiar character: the more convincing they are, the less they are likely to be invoked. The US never had to pay off the debt it incurred when it converted the debt of individual states into Federal obligations. Germany has been willing to do only the minimum; that is why it had to keep escalating its commitments and is incurring actual losses. The fiscal compact, backed up by a well functioning fiscal authority would practically eliminate the risk of default. eurobonds would compare favorably with the bonds of US, UK and Japan in the financial markets. Admittedly, Germany would have to pay more on its own debt than it does today but the exceptionally low yields on Bunds is a symptom of the disease plaguing the periphery. The indirect benefit Germany would derive from the recovery of the periphery would far outweigh the additional cost incurred on its own national debt.

 

To be sure, eurobonds are not a panacea. First of all, the fiscal compact itself is an ill-designed instrument. The introduction of eurobonds would give the eurozone a boost but that may not be enough. In that case some additional fiscal and or monetary stimulus would be needed. But it would be a luxury to have such a problem.

 

Second, the European Union also needs a banking union and eventually a political union. The Cyprus rescue made these needs more acute by calling into question the business model of European banks that relies heavily on large deposits. But the introduction of eurobonds would be a step in the right direction. Germany accepting eurobonds would totally change the political atmosphere and pave the way to the additional steps.

 

The most profound deficiency The main limitation of eurobonds is that they would not eliminate the divergences in competitiveness. Individual countries would still need to undertake structural reforms. Those that fail to do so would turn into permanent pockets of poverty and dependency similar to the ones that persist in many rich countries. They would survive on limited support from European Structural Funds and remittances. But Germany accepting eurobonds would totally change the political atmosphere and facilitate the structural reforms that are also needed. Reforms work better when trading partners are prosperous than in conditions of widespread decline. Eurobonds offer a promising environment to structural reforms that are also needed.

 

The fact remains that the large majority of the German public is adamantly opposed to eurobonds. Since chancellor Merkel vetoed eurobonds, the arguments I have put forward here have not even been considered. People don't realize that agreeing to eurobonds would be much less costly than doing only the minimum to preserve the euro. That is how misconceptions can become engrained in public opinion.

 

It is up to Germany to decide whether it is willing to authorise eurobonds or not. But it has no right to prevent the heavily indebted countries from escaping their misery by banding together and issuing eurobonds. In other words, if Germany is opposed to eurobonds it should consider leaving the euro and letting the others introduce them.

 

This exercise would yield a surprising result: eurobonds issued by a eurozone that excludes Germany would still compare favorably with those of the US, UK and Japan. The net debt of these three countries as a proportion of their GDP is actually higher than that of the eurozone excluding Germany.

 

This surprising result can be explained by comparing the consequences of Germany leaving the euro to a heavily indebted country, like Italy, leaving.

 

Since all the accumulated debt is denominated in euros, it makes all the difference which country remains in charge of the euro. If Germany left, the euro would depreciate. The debtor countries would regain their competitiveness. Their debt would diminish in real terms and, if they issued eurobonds, the threat of default would disappear.  Their debt would suddenly become sustainable. Most of the burden of adjustment would fall on the countries that left the euro. Their exports would become less competitive and they would encounter stiff competition from the euro area in their home markets. They would also incur losses on their claims and investments denominated in euro. The extent of their losses would depend on the extent of the depreciation; therefore they would have an interest in keeping the depreciation within bounds. After initial dislocations, the eventual outcome would fulfill John Maynard Keynes' dream of an international currency system in which both creditors and debtors share responsibility for maintaining stability. And Europe would escape the looming depression.

 

By contrast, if Italy left, its euro-denominated debt burden would become unsustainable and it would have to be restructured. This would plunge the rest of Europe and the rest of the world into a financial meltdown, which may well prove beyond the capacity of the monetary authorities to contain. The collapse of the euro would likely lead to the disorderly disintegration of the European Union and Europe would be left worse off than it had been when it embarked on the noble experiment of creating a European Union.

 

Obviously, it would be better for Germany to leave than Italy and equally obviously, it would be better for Germany to agree to eurobonds than to leave the Euro. The trouble is that Germany has not been put to the choice, and it has another alternative at its disposal: it can continue along the current course, always doing the minimum to preserve the euro, but nothing more.

 

If my analysis is correct that is not the best alternative even for Germany, except in the very near term. The situation is deteriorating and eventually it is bound to become unsustainable. The longer it takes, the greater the damage. Nevertheless, that is Germany's preferred choice, at least until after the elections.

 

There is a strong case for Germany to make a definitive choice whether to agree to eurobonds or to leave the euro. That is the case I came here to argue.

 

I reflected long and hard whether I should present my case now or wait until after the elections. In the end I decided to go ahead, based on two considerations. One is that events have their own dynamics and the crisis is likely to become more acute even before the elections. The Cyprus rescue proved me right. The other is that my interpretation of events is so radically different from the one that prevails in Germany that it will take time for it to sink in and the sooner I start the better.

 

Let me sum up my argument. I contend that Europe would be better off if Germany decided between eurobonds and exit than if it continued on its current course of doing the minimum to hold the euro together. That holds true whether Germany agreed to eurobonds or decided to leave the euro; and it holds true not only for Europe but also for Germany, except in the very near term.

 

Which of the two alternatives is better for Germany is less clear-cut. Only the German electorate is qualified to decide. If a referendum were called today the eurosceptics would win hands down. But more intensive consideration could change people's mind. They would discover that the cost to Germany of authorising eurobonds has been greatly exaggerated and the cost of leaving the euro understated.

 

To state my own views, my first preference is eurobonds; my second is Germany leaving the euro. Either choice is infinitely better than not making a choice and perpetuating the crisis. Worst of all would be for a debtor country, like Italy, to leave the euro because it would lead to the disorderly dissolution of the European Union. 

 

I have made some surprising assertions; notably how well eurobonds could work even without Germany. My pro-European friends simply cannot believe it. They can't imagine a euro without Germany. I think they are conflating the euro with the European Union. The two are not identical. The European Union is the goal and the euro is a means to an end. Therefore the euro ought not to be allowed to destroy the European Union.

 

But I may be too rational in my analysis. The European Union is conflated with the euro not only in popular narratives but also in law. Consequently the European Union may not survive Germany leaving the euro. In that case we must all do what we can to persuade the German public to abandon some of its most ingrained prejudices and misconceptions and accept eurobonds.

 

I should like to end by emphasising how important the European Union is not only for Europe, but for the world. The EU was meant to be the embodiment of the principles of open society. That means that perfect knowledge is unattainable. Nobody is free of prejudices and misconceptions; nobody should be blamed for having made mistakes. The blame or Schuld begins only when a mistake or misconception is identified but not corrected. That is when the principles on which the European Union was built are betrayed. It is in that spirit that Germany should agree to eurobonds and save the European Union.

• George Soros is chairman of Soros Fund Management and of the Open Society Foundations.

Copyright: Project Syndicate, 2013.


guardian.co.uk © 2013 Guardian News and Media Limited or its affiliated companies. All rights reserved. | Use of this content is subject to our Terms & Conditions | More Feeds


READ THE ORIGINAL POST AT www.guardian.co.uk

How to save the European Union | George Soros

There is a strong case for Germany to make a definitive choice whether to accept eurobonds or to leave the euro
The speech in full

The euro crisis has already transformed the European Union from a voluntary association of equal states into a creditor-debtor relationship from which there is no easy escape. The creditors stand to lose large sums should a member state exit the union, yet debtors are subjected to policies that deepen their depression, aggravate their debt burden and perpetuate their subordinate position. As a result, the crisis is now threatening to destroy the European Union. That would be a tragedy of historic proportions which can only be prevented with German leadership.

The causes of the crisis are so complicated that they boggle the mind. They cannot be properly understood without realising the crucial role that mistakes and misconceptions have played in creating them.The fatal flaw of the euro is that by creating an independent central bank, member countries have become indebted in a currency that they don't control. The risk of default relegates some member countries to the status of third world countries that became over-indebted in a foreign currency. This feature of the euro was ignored both by the authorities and market participants until the Greek crisis and it is still not properly understood today.

At first, both the authorities and market participants treated all government bonds as if they were riskless, creating a perverse incentive for banks to load up on the weaker bonds. When Greece revealed the extent of its deficit, financial markets discovered the risk of sovereign debt default and raised risk premiums not only on Greek bonds but on the bonds of all heavily indebted euro members with a vengeance. Since European banks were heavily loaded with exactly those bonds, this precipitated a twin sovereign debt and banking crisis.

Subsequently the so-called periphery countries were treated as if they were solely responsible for their misfortunes and the structural defects of the euro remained uncorrected. Germany and the other creditor countries did the minimum necessary to preserve the euro but they continued to apply the treaties that proved to be flawed and imposed new rules that prolonged and aggravated the recession. The pain and suffering is almost entirely self-inflicted by the eurozone. It has the quality of a nightmare.

The burden of responsibility falls mainly on Germany. The Bundesbank helped design the blueprint for the euro, whose defects put Germany into the driver's seat. This has created two problems. One is political, the other financial. It is the combination of the two that has rendered the situation so intractable.

The political problem is that Germany did not seek the dominant position into which it has been thrust and it is unwilling to accept the obligations and liabilities that go with it. Germany understandably doesn't want to be the "deep pocket" for the euro. So it extends just enough support to avoid default but nothing more, and as soon as the pressure from the financial markets abates it seeks to tighten the conditions on which the support is given.

The financial problem is that Germany is imposing the wrong policies on the eurozone. Austerity doesn't work. You cannot shrink the debt burden by shrinking the budget deficit. The debt burden is a ratio between the accumulated debt and the GDP, both expressed in nominal terms. And in conditions of inadequate demand, budget cuts cause a more than proportionate reduction in the GDP – in technical terms the so-called fiscal multiplier is greater than one. This means for every that for every million euro reduction in the budget deficit, the country's GDP falls by more than a million euros, leading to a rise in the ration of national debt to GDP.

The German public finds this difficult to understand. The fiscal and structural reforms undertaken by the Schröder government worked in 2006; why shouldn't they work for the eurozone a few years later? The answer is that austerity for a single country works by increasing its exports and reducing its imports. When everybody is doing the same thing it simply doesn't work: it is clearly impossible for all members of the eurozone to improve their balance of trade with one another.

In the bailout of Cyprus, Germany went too far. In order to minimise the cost of the bailout it insisted on bailing in bank depositors. This was premature. If it had happened after a banking union had been established and the banks recapitalised, it might have been a healthy reform. But it came at a time when the banking system was retreating into national silos and remained very vulnerable. What happened in Cyprus undermined the business model of European banks, which relies heavily on deposits. Until now the authorities went out of their way to protect depositors. Cyprus has changed that. Attention is focused on the impact of the rescue on Cyprus but the impact on the banking system is far more important. Banks will have to pay risk premiums that will fall more heavily on weaker banks and the banks of weaker countries. The insidious link between the cost of sovereign debt and bank debt will be reinforced and a banking union that would re-establish a more level playing field will be more difficult to attain.

Chancellor Merkel would have liked to put the euro crisis on ice at least until after the elections, but it is back in force. The German public may be unaware of this because Cyprus was a tremendous political victory for chancellor Merkel. No country will dare to challenge her will. Moreover, Germany itself remains relatively unaffected by the deepening depression that is enveloping the eurozone. I expect, however, that by the time of the elections Germany will also be in recession. That is because the monetary policy pursued by the eurozone is out of sync with the other major currencies. The others are engaged in quantitative easing. The Bank of Japan was the last holdout but it changed sides recently. A weaker yen coupled with the weakness in Europe is bound to affect Germany's exports.

The solution for all these problems of the eurozone can be summed up in one word: eurobonds. If countries that abide by the fiscal compact were allowed to convert their entire stock of government debt into eurobonds, the positive impact would be little short of the miraculous. The danger of default would disappear and so would the risk premiums. The balance sheets of the banks would receive an immediate boost and so would the budgets of the heavily indebted countries. Italy, for instance, would save up to 4% of its GDP. Its budget would move into surplus and fiscal stimulus would replace austerity. Its economy would grow and its debt ratio would fall. Most of the seemingly intractable problems would vanish into thin air. It would be truly like waking from a nightmare.

With some modification, the fiscal compact would provide adequate safeguards against the risks involved in a joint and several obligation. It would allow member countries to issue new eurobonds only to replace maturing ones, but nothing more; after five years the outstanding debt would be gradually reduced to 60% of GDP. Non-compliant countries would be penalised by restricting the amount of eurobonds they are allowed to issue, forcing them to borrow the balance in their own name and pay heavy risk premiums – a powerful inducement to adhere to the fiscal compact's terms.

Eurobonds would not ruin Germany's credit rating. On the contrary, they would favorably compare with the bonds of the United States, the United Kingdom, and Japan.

Eurobonds are not a panacea. First of all, the fiscal compact itself needs some modifications to ensure that the penalties are automatic, prompt and not too severe to be credible. Second, the boost derived from eurobonds may not be sufficient, necessitating additional stimulus but it would be a luxury to have such a problem. Third, the European Union also needs a banking union and eventually a political union. The Cyprus rescue made these needs more acute by calling into question the business model of European banks that relies heavily on large deposits. The main limitation of eurobonds is that they would not eliminate the divergences in competiveness. But Germany accepting eurobonds would totally change the political atmosphere and facilitate structural reforms. Unfortunately Germany is adamantly opposed to eurobonds. Since chancellor Merkel vetoed them, the arguments put forward here have not even been considered. People don't realise that agreeing to eurobonds would be much less costly than doing only the minimum to preserve the euro.

It is up to Germany to decide whether it is willing to authorise eurobonds or not. But it has no right to prevent the heavily indebted countries from escaping their misery by banding together and issuing eurobonds. In other words, if Germany is opposed to eurobonds it should consider leaving the euro and letting the others introduce them.

This exercise would yield a surprising result: eurobonds issued by a eurozone that excludes Germany and other like-minded countries would still compare favourably with those of the US, UK and Japan.

Let me explain why. SSince all the accumulated debt is denominated in euros, it makes all the difference which country remains in charge of the euro. If Germany left, the euro would depreciate. The debtor countries would regain their competitiveness. Their debt would diminish in real terms and, if they issued eurobonds, the threat of default would disappear. Their debt would suddenly become sustainable. Most of the burden of adjustment would fall on the countries that left the euro. Their exports would become less competitive and they would encounter stiff competition from the euro area in their home markets.

By contrast, if Italy left, its euro-denominated debt burden would become unsustainable and would have to be restructured. This would plunge the global financial system into a meltdown, which may well prove beyond the capacity of the monetary authorities to contain. The collapse of the euro would likely lead to the disorderly disintegration of the European Union and Europe would be left worse off than it had been when it embarked on the noble experiment of creating a European Union. So, if anyone must leave it should be Germany, not Italy.

There is a strong case for Germany to make a definitive choice whether to accept eurobonds or to leave the euro. The trouble is that Germany has not been put to the choice, and it has another alternative at its disposal: it can continue along the current course, always doing the minimum to preserve the euro, but nothing more. That is not the best alternative even for Germany, except perhaps in the very near term. Nevertheless, that is chancellor Merkel's preferred choice, at least until after the elections.

In sum, I contend that Europe would be infinitely better off if Germany made a definite choice between accepting eurobonds or leaving the euro. That holds true whether Germany chose eurobonds or exit; and it holds true not only for Europe but also for Germany, except perhaps in the very near term. Which of the two alternatives is better for Germany is less clear-cut. Only the German electorate is qualified to decide.

If a referendum were called today the eurosceptics would win hands down. But more intensive consideration could change people's mind. They would discover that authorising eurobonds would actually benefit Germany and the cost of leaving the euro has been greatly understated.

I have made some surprising assertions; notably how well eurobonds could work even without Germany. My pro-European friends simply cannot believe it. They can't imagine a euro without Germany. I think they are conflating the euro with the European Union. The two are not identical. The European Union is the goal and the euro is a means to an end. Therefore the euro ought not to be allowed to destroy the European Union.

But I may be too rational in my analysis. The European Union is conflated with the euro not only in popular narratives but also in law. Consequently the European Union may not survive Germany leaving the euro. In that case the German public needs to be persuaded to abandon some of its most ingrained prejudices and misconceptions and accept eurobonds.

I should like to emphasise how important the European Union is not only for Europe, but for the world. The EU was meant to be the embodiment of the principles of open society. That means that perfect knowledge is unattainable. Nobody is free of prejudices and misconceptions; nobody should be blamed for having made mistakes. The blame begins only when a mistake or misconception is identified but not corrected. That is when the principles on which the European Union was built are betrayed. It is in that spirit that Germany should agree to eurobonds and save the European Union.

• George Soros is chairman of Soros Fund Management and of the Open Society Foundations.

Copyright: Project Syndicate, 2013.


guardian.co.uk © 2013 Guardian News and Media Limited or its affiliated companies. All rights reserved. | Use of this content is subject to our Terms & Conditions | More Feeds


READ THE ORIGINAL POST AT www.guardian.co.uk

Greek Claims Of German War Reparations Owed: Not Very Convincing

I had though that this subject would disappear into the long grass. But apparently not: the Greek Government really has been calculating the war reparations that Germany supposedly owes the country. It's certainly a large number but I think the chances of any of it ever being paid are around and about zero:

READ THE ORIGINAL POST AT www.forbes.com

International Budget Guide 2013: Athens, Greece


International Budget Guide 2013: Athens, Greece
Gadling
The Antikythera shipwreck exhibit. The National Archaeological Museum already boasts some of the most important artworks and artifacts from ancient Greece, and this temporary exhibit provides another compelling reason to visit. The Antikythera ...


READ THE ORIGINAL POST AT www.gadling.com

Police: Greece man assaulted four-month-old baby


News 10NBC

Police: Greece man assaulted four-month-old baby
News 10NBC
A 20-year-old Greece man is facing charges after police say he assaulted a four-month-old baby and adult female. Akil Mabry is charged with second and third-degree assault and endangering the welfare of a child. Greece Police tell News10NBC the ...


READ THE ORIGINAL POST AT www.whec.com

Travel news round up Get to Greece for an Orthodox Easter treat


Travel news round up Get to Greece for an Orthodox Easter treat
Mirror.co.uk
On Crete, Greece's most southerly island, 8 to 10 hours' sunshine are standard in May. In Armeni, near Souda Bay, the village will be the focus of traditional celebrations. Villa Amvrosia, a 20-minute stroll away, is set in pretty gardens with views ...


READ THE ORIGINAL POST AT www.mirror.co.uk

The Greek Stock Market Is On A Massive Tear Today


Business Insider

The Greek Stock Market Is On A Massive Tear Today
Business Insider
The "troika" of lenders at the EU, the ECB, and the IMF are back in Greece, and the Greek stock market is up 5.4 percent today. On Sunday, the troika and the Greek government froze a plan to merge Greece's two largest banks, National Bank of Greece and ...
Greek bank recaps may stabilize funding, raise ratings, says FitchKathimerini
Greek bank stocks plunge as merger is frozenLos Angeles Times
Greek bank stocks plunge after merger stalledCBS Moneywatch
Financial Times -Telegraph.co.uk -Reuters UK
all 74 news articles »

READ THE ORIGINAL POST AT www.businessinsider.com

Greece enters deflation for first time in 45 years


Telegraph.co.uk

Greece enters deflation for first time in 45 years
Telegraph.co.uk
The fall was widely expected as a consequence of five years of unrelenting economic contraction in Greece, where GDP is 16pc smaller than it was in 2008, but could mark the beginning of a dangerous deflationary spiral for the fragile economy. "Given ...
Greek inflation turns negative, first time in 45 yearsReuters

all 8 news articles »

READ THE ORIGINAL POST AT www.telegraph.co.uk

Negative inflation in Greece from deep recession


euronews

Negative inflation in Greece from deep recession
euronews
Greece is in its sixth year of recession, hit by austerity policies imposed under a bailout from the European Union and International Monetary Fund which is keeping it from going bankrupt. The government is forecasting the economy will contract by 4.5 ...


READ THE ORIGINAL POST AT www.euronews.com

Germany welcomes southern Europe's best and brightest into its workforce

Young graduates from Greece, Spain and Portugal head north as home employment prospects remain bleak

Unemployment rates continue to break records in the eurozone, and there is little chance of an improvement this year. The crisis in the jobs market across Europe is hitting young people hardest, setting in motion new migratory patterns between Mediterranean countries and the north.

Germany stands out as an exception. Despite sluggish growth in the EU's largest economy, unemployment is steady: good news that won't fall on deaf ears. In the past two years, the net number of people entering Germany rose from 128,000 to 340,000. German businesses are drawing on a fresh source of cheap, qualified labour from Greece and Spain.

After five years in higher education, Paschalis Lampridis, 25, left Greece – and its labour market devastated by recession and austerity – and headed for Frankfurt, the business capital of a country where companies are still producing, investing and, above all, hiring. That was a year ago. Now, working as a computer programmer for the tyre firm Continental, Lampridis refuses to indulge in nostalgia. Obviously, he sometimes dreams of sea and sun. The winter in Frankfurt has been overcast and persistently cold, but, he says, "There was no future for me at home."

The statistics endorse this view. Unemployment is soaring in Greece and Spain, with more than one in four out of work. Youth is bearing the brunt of the downturn, with more than half the active population under 25 jobless. Meanwhile, the German labour market is buoyant. According to figures published by the federal employment agency in February, unemployment is steady at 6.9%.

Tens of thousands of young people from southern Europe have followed the same path as Lampridis. In the first nine months of 2012, 27,000 Spaniards, 26,300 Greeks and almost 10,000 Portuguese moved to Germany. The Germans have already found a name for them, neue Gastarbeiter (new guest workers), a throwback to the immigrants who flocked to West Germany in the 1960s, leaving their homes in Turkey and southern Europe to staff the machines of the economic miracle.

However, the new generation differs from its predecessors. Today's migrants are younger and better qualified. Lampridis had to overcome his "terror" of a difficult language and settle in. "To begin with, I could only understand about a third of what people were saying," he says. "But they know the value of good work here."

Elena Dolaptsi, 23, is a fully qualified childminder. She has travelled the same road as her parents did 10 years earlier, but in the opposite direction. Homesick after years of casual labour in Frankfurt they finally returned home to Drama, in the Greek region of east Macedonia. At the time, the Greek economy was in better shape whereas Germany, with almost 5 million unemployed, was the "sick man of Europe".

That has all changed now. Battered by the current crisis, the lifeblood of Greece is ebbing away. "If I'd wanted to stay, my only option would have been to settle on an island and make do with €400 [$520] a month in wages," Dolaptsi explains in her still hesitant German. So she chose to try her luck in Germany. She arrived in January and started work in a nursery in a small town near Frankfurt. To find a job, she answered seven adverts and received six positive responses.

German business is thriving but the population is growing old, resulting in an increasingly acute shortage of labour. The country is desperately looking for qualified personnel to staff its factories, research laboratories, hospitals and kindergartens. According to experts, at least 400,000 newcomers (in the net migration balance) will be needed every year to compensate for ageing and to maintain current economic trends.

Southern Europe has a massive reserve of young talent with poor prospects. The Frankfurt area, on the other hand, is prosperous – thanks to its banks, car and chemical industries but also its trade fairs, where valuable deals are settled. In a drive to attract the personnel it needs, the Hesse region finalised a partnership agreement with the Madrid area last autumn. The scheme includes crash courses in German for people less concerned about the finer points of the language than with technical and financial vocabulary. But the partnership will also bring Spanish apprentices to local firms. A website has gone live to help newcomers complete administrative formalities and find lodgings.

German business leaders have taken to attending job fairs in Spain. Invenio is a medium-sized German operation – with a workforce of 580 – that specialises in outsourcing its engineers to larger companies. Currently enjoying rapid growth, it has had to turn down contracts for lack of sufficient human resources. So it too has started looking for staff in Spain. In recent months, Invenio has hired about 20 Spanish graduates and intends to find more. "They are highly motivated and bring a different outlook with them," says the company's CEO, Kai Wissler.

But things do not always go quite so smoothly for these economic refugees. Many land in a foreign country with no money, work, qualifications or connections. Quite a few knock on the door of Athenagoras Ziliaskopoulos, the head of Frankfurt's Greek Orthodox community. They are looking for advice, a decent translation or maybe even a roof over their heads. Since 2009, the priest has provided emergency lodging in the church for hundreds of his compatriots.

"A lot of them are under some sort of misconception," Ziliaskopoulos says. "They think they can find work just by stopping someone in the street." He usually firmly suggests that the poorest applicants go home, paying for a bus or plane ticket out of community funds. He reckons the only ones who stand a chance are mobile and adaptable graduates, who ideally speak several languages. Indeed, in their case exile is probably the only solution, he adds with a sigh.

But is Germany not in danger of alienating its partners in the south by attracting their best brains? "You mustn't imagine we're happy about the situation there," says Wissler. "One day these young people will be able to go home with the benefit of the experience they have gained here, rather than having to endure years of unemployment."

Lampridis has no plans to return to Greece in the near future, unless he is sent there by a foreign company with pay on a par with German earnings … like an expatriate in his home country.

• This article appeared in Guardian Weekly, which incorporates material from Le Monde


guardian.co.uk © 2013 Guardian News and Media Limited or its affiliated companies. All rights reserved. | Use of this content is subject to our Terms & Conditions | More Feeds


READ THE ORIGINAL POST AT www.guardian.co.uk